温莎日记 15

Aid-for-trade facilitation

The increasingly important constellation of issues surrounding trade, aid, and development policies, as well as the increased attention to aid effectiveness and aid for trade in negotiations and other multilateral forums is the motivation for this research. The linkages between trade facilitation, trade, and development are relatively simple in theory. Development is enhanced through income growth, which comes from the expansion of trade, investment, and production opportunities. Trade facilitation initiatives, with the aim of lowering trade transactions costs, can enhance trade competitiveness and expand trade flows, while at the same time playing an important role in supporting a positive business climate. But, in practice, implementing trade facilitation initiatives involves the domestic reform agenda, private sector priorities, and national development strategies. Trade facilitation reform requires self-assessment, technical assistance, and capacity building. In summary, trade facilitation enhances trade, but are difficult to do and cost money.

Empirical research on trade facilitation has largely focused on the question: What is trade facilitation and how does it work to enhance trade? A number of studies provide strong evidence that improvements in trade facilitation—for example improvement in port and information infrastructures, more rapid customs clearance time, or regulatory reform to remove duplicative technical requirements on imports—have a positive impact on trade performance. In bringing together the strands of the literature on trade facilitation and trade, and on aid and trade, our research in this paper finds strong empirical evidence that aid directed to the trade facilitation reform agenda has a small, but significant and positive relationship to trade flows, particularly exports of the recipient countries. The bulk of the relationship between aid and trade appears to come from a narrow set of aid flows directed toward trade policy and regulatory reform, within the overall flow of aid for trade directed toward sectoral development or infrastructure.

The majority of econometric empirical studies on the topic of trade facilitation conclude that improvements in trade facilitation measures are associated with reductions in trade costs and increases in trade flows. The various trade facilitation measures examined—streamlining customs procedures, improving port efficiency, harmonizing to international standards, and other reforms—work through different channels to lower trade costs for importers and exporters and not surprisingly, a country’s trade flows may be more strongly responsive to one set of reforms less so to others. Case studies of trade facilitation reforms in specific countries are valuable as they can explicitly address and estimate the costs of engaging in detailed reform and also consider the benefits of specific reform measures. Endogeneity could run the other direction—from trade to aid—in that some donors allocate aid to those countries with whom they have the strongest trade ties.

Recent surveys conclude that the econometric estimates of whether aid induces a ‘‘Dutch disease’’ phenomenon can vary widely. We link aid-for-trade facilitation flows to trade flows through the black box that relates aid to trade facilitation reform: Certain types of aid flows promote certain reforms or change certain infrastructures which reduce trade transaction costs and thus enhance trade flows. The issue of aid-induced Dutch disease, while relevant in a broader context, is not likely to be an issue in our analysis. This is due to the fact that aid delivered for the trade facilitation goals examined here, in contrast to other aid objectives, is numerically small and therefore unlikely to precipitate any real exchange rate appreciation. With respect to the effectiveness of export promotion agencies, Lederman et al. (2006) find that EPAs, on average, have a positive and statistically significant impact on exports. Nevertheless, they find that the impact is heterogeneous across regions: larger effects were found in Latin American and Asian agencies, while agencies in sub-Saharan African, the Middle East and North Africa lag behind. Cali and te Velde (2011) also focus on exporting only and use more aggregated aid flows.

The OECD-CRS reporting system map data into three categories that match the aid-for-trade agenda:

Trade policy and regulation (US$ 296 million in 2005): Comprises aid flows to facilitate the participation in multilateral trade negotiations and to improve the implementation of multilateral trade agreements. Furthermore, it contains all support to mainstream trade policy, including technical standards, customs regimes, and tariff structure.

Trade development (US$ 2,910 million in 2005): This category covers business development and activities aimed at improving the business climate, access to trade finance, and trade promotion in the sectors of agriculture, forestry, fishing, industry, mining, tourism, and services.

Economic infrastructure (US$ 5,586 million in 2005): All aid flows directed toward the improvement of the infrastructure for transport, storage, communications and energy.

The gravity equation approach that we use requires some additional variables. For the main analysis, our data set combines information from the World Integrated Trade Solution (WITS) database for trade flows and Trade Analysis and Information System (TRAINS) database for tariffs, the World Development Indicators (WDI) data set for GDP data, and the OECD-CRS for aid flows. For robustness checks, we use additional country-specific data, including distances between trading partners, and other country-specific data, such as a country’s area and language from the Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales, and population data from the WDI.

From basic microeconomic principles, they derive a gravity-like model of exports from country i to country j in sector k(X_{ij}^k ):(1) log(X_{ij}^k )=log(E_{j}^k )+log(Y_{i}^k )-log(Y^k)-(1-\sigma _{k} )log(t_{ij}^k )-log(Y^k)-(1-\sigma _{k} )log(P_{j}^k )-log(Y^k)-(1-\sigma _{k} )log(\Pi _{i}^k )+\varepsilon _{ij}^k

The data requirements for the multilateral resistance terms exceed what is generally available; a common solution is to use some variant on fixed-effects estimation. Fixed effects could be country-specific (for each importer and exporter) or bilateral fixed effects (for each bilateral country pair in the sample). Bilateral fixed effects capture many of the standard variables included in gravity equations, such as distance, language, colonial ties, which are then dropped. Bilateral fixed effects also imply that the multilateral resistance terms are unchanging over time. Our research exploits the time-series variation in the trade and aid data to investigate their relationships but we recognize that the donor–recipient relationship can vary over time and there can be global factors affecting trade values. So, we incorporate both time fixed effects as well as bilateral fixed effects that are time- varying (e.g., we allow the Anderson and van Wincoop resistance term to vary over time). The time-varying bilateral fixed effects are calculated as 5-year averages since annual time-varying bilateral fixed effects are not feasible given the bilateral pairing of both trade and aid data.

We are now able to postulate that bilateral imports t_{ijt} are a function of the country-specific variables and our baseline empirical specification therefore takes the following form:(2) log(t_{ijt} )=\alpha _{ijt} +\beta _1log(Y_{it} )+\beta _2 log(Y_{jt} )+\beta _3log(1+\tau _{it} )+\beta _4log(IAFT_{it} )+\beta _5log(EAFT_{jt} )+\beta _6(IOA_{it} )+\beta _7log(EOA_{jt} )+\gamma _t
+\varepsilon _{ijt}

In this section, we consider several different permutations of our main specification. The first step is simply to establish whether aid-for-trade facilitation flows are related to trade flows. The second step considers whether this relationship is different for different country groups, in particular focusing on the tied-aid issue. The third question relates to lagged effects of aid. Finally, we consider how the relationship between aid-for-trade facilitation and trade flows might vary with the type of aid flow (narrow, broad, or hard, soft).

Table 1 shows estimation results using the all positive trade flows for 167 importers (reporters) and 172 exporters (partners) for the years 1990 to 2005 in column 1 and 2 and then in subsequent columns several different permutations of countries receiving aid-for-trade facilitation. In the first two columns, the common gravity variables, such as GDP and tariff, have the expected signs and magnitude. The significance level of our variables of interest changes only slightly, the magnitude of the import coefficient is a bit lower, but the sum of the coefficient estimates is about the same.

There are several additional ways to cut the data to examine the relationship between aid-for-trade facilitation and trade flows. Column 3 considers just the aid recipients and all their trading partners. Both of the aid-for-trade coefficients are larger than for the baseline specification of all countries, suggesting that trade flows between aid-for-trade facilitation recipients and their trading partners have a relatively higher elasticity with respect to aid than non-recipients. The coefficient for aid-for-trade facilitation for the exporter is statistically larger than that for aid-for-trade facilitation for the importer, suggesting that aid-for-trade facilitation is balance-of-payments enhancing.

Table 1 Baseline estimation results (bilateral 5-years fixed effects and year fixed effects included)

With regard to Other Aid, it remains positively associated with imports, but is negatively associated with exports within the ‘south–south’ trading group. On balance, whereas ‘south–south’ trade appears to be greater with aid-for-trade facilitation flow, Other Aid may work against such trade. When intra-donor trade is completely removed from the sample, the coefficient for aid-for-trade facilitation for importers continues to be insignificant; unlike the previous column where donors were not included, this permutation makes clear that tied aid is not likely associated with aid-for-trade facilitation. Moreover, the magnitude of the coefficient aid-for-trade facilitation for exporters remains at the baseline value. Column 6 investigates whether time lags affect the relationship between aid and trade. Aid may not become effective immediately, but only after a certain period of time. Introducing time lags reduces the sample size due to several gaps in the aid flow data. Running the same regression specification on this smaller sample, yields coefficient magnitudes similar in profile to columns 1 and 2. The sum of the two coefficients is about the same as the sample without lags.

All told, the evidence suggests that controlling for Other Aid, aid-for-trade facilitation is associated with both more exports and more imports by recipient countries; the magnitude of this relation is higher for exports. When considering trade between recipients and donors, excluding intra-donor trade, the relationship between aid and exports is a bit larger than just considering trade among the aid recipients, whereas the statistical significance of any relationship between aid-for- trade facilitation and imports disappears. This suggests an important role for aid-for-trade facilitation to enable exports to both the developed and developing world.

The Trade Policy and Regulations, our ‘narrow’ type of aid assistance, is targeted explicitly toward enhancing the trade policy system in countries—their ability to navigate TBT, SPS, and TRIPS. These types of aid flows are focused on customs, transparency, and government procurement. Aid is directed toward learning to negotiate market access, implement RTAs, address dispute settlement, and accession issues. Thus, this type of aid-for-trade facilitation is narrowly focused on the country as it directly interacts with the trading system itself. Therefore, this aid might have a relatively stronger relationship to trade flows because it is targeted directly to trading system issues.

If we assume that the estimated coefficients apply to aid and trade in the year 2008, we can simulate the relationship between a 1% increase in aid-for-trade facilitation (in USD terms) to recipient countries’ exports. Using the trade flows and amount of aid-for-trade facilitation for the year 2008 and applying them to our elasticities of ln_EAFT, we obtain simulation results which can be summarized as follows:

In 2008, aid-for-trade facilitation amounted to about US$ 21.9 billion. Our simulations suggest that a 1% increase in aid (US$ 219 million) can be associated with about US$ 291 million of additional exports for aid-receiving countries. This means that US$ 1 of aid for trade can be associated with US$1.33 of additional exports for recipient countries.

Consider the narrow definition of aid-for-trade facilitation, that is consider only aid-for-trade policy reform and regulatory reform which amounted to US$ 486 million in 2008. According to our simulations, a 1% increase in this type of aid (US$ 4.86 million) can be associated with an increase in exports of aid-receiving countries of about US$ 347 million.

Targeted aid-for-trade facilitation appears to be particularly well suited to raising exports, even as it raises imports too—making this kind of aid balance-of-payments enhancing. Aid-for-trade facilitation appears to be more strongly related to trade, particularly exports, of the recipient countries compared to global trade, which means that such aid is hitting the target. Simulations suggest that US$ 1 of aid-for-trade facilitation can be associated with US$ 1.33 of additional exports for recipient countries. In contrast, general aid flows appear to be more strongly correlated with imports relative to exports—and being larger in magnitude, this suggests that overall aid may not enhance the balance of payments. Ongoing dialogue to address coordination and monitoring of trade-related aid and overall aid should consider our results, particularly in regards to targeting aid to promote its greatest relationship to trade.

最后编辑于
©著作权归作者所有,转载或内容合作请联系作者
禁止转载,如需转载请通过简信或评论联系作者。
  • 序言:七十年代末,一起剥皮案震惊了整个滨河市,随后出现的几起案子,更是在滨河造成了极大的恐慌,老刑警刘岩,带你破解...
    沈念sama阅读 204,293评论 6 478
  • 序言:滨河连续发生了三起死亡事件,死亡现场离奇诡异,居然都是意外死亡,警方通过查阅死者的电脑和手机,发现死者居然都...
    沈念sama阅读 85,604评论 2 381
  • 文/潘晓璐 我一进店门,熙熙楼的掌柜王于贵愁眉苦脸地迎上来,“玉大人,你说我怎么就摊上这事。” “怎么了?”我有些...
    开封第一讲书人阅读 150,958评论 0 337
  • 文/不坏的土叔 我叫张陵,是天一观的道长。 经常有香客问我,道长,这世上最难降的妖魔是什么? 我笑而不...
    开封第一讲书人阅读 54,729评论 1 277
  • 正文 为了忘掉前任,我火速办了婚礼,结果婚礼上,老公的妹妹穿的比我还像新娘。我一直安慰自己,他们只是感情好,可当我...
    茶点故事阅读 63,719评论 5 366
  • 文/花漫 我一把揭开白布。 她就那样静静地躺着,像睡着了一般。 火红的嫁衣衬着肌肤如雪。 梳的纹丝不乱的头发上,一...
    开封第一讲书人阅读 48,630评论 1 281
  • 那天,我揣着相机与录音,去河边找鬼。 笑死,一个胖子当着我的面吹牛,可吹牛的内容都是我干的。 我是一名探鬼主播,决...
    沈念sama阅读 38,000评论 3 397
  • 文/苍兰香墨 我猛地睁开眼,长吁一口气:“原来是场噩梦啊……” “哼!你这毒妇竟也来了?” 一声冷哼从身侧响起,我...
    开封第一讲书人阅读 36,665评论 0 258
  • 序言:老挝万荣一对情侣失踪,失踪者是张志新(化名)和其女友刘颖,没想到半个月后,有当地人在树林里发现了一具尸体,经...
    沈念sama阅读 40,909评论 1 299
  • 正文 独居荒郊野岭守林人离奇死亡,尸身上长有42处带血的脓包…… 初始之章·张勋 以下内容为张勋视角 年9月15日...
    茶点故事阅读 35,646评论 2 321
  • 正文 我和宋清朗相恋三年,在试婚纱的时候发现自己被绿了。 大学时的朋友给我发了我未婚夫和他白月光在一起吃饭的照片。...
    茶点故事阅读 37,726评论 1 330
  • 序言:一个原本活蹦乱跳的男人离奇死亡,死状恐怖,灵堂内的尸体忽然破棺而出,到底是诈尸还是另有隐情,我是刑警宁泽,带...
    沈念sama阅读 33,400评论 4 321
  • 正文 年R本政府宣布,位于F岛的核电站,受9级特大地震影响,放射性物质发生泄漏。R本人自食恶果不足惜,却给世界环境...
    茶点故事阅读 38,986评论 3 307
  • 文/蒙蒙 一、第九天 我趴在偏房一处隐蔽的房顶上张望。 院中可真热闹,春花似锦、人声如沸。这庄子的主人今日做“春日...
    开封第一讲书人阅读 29,959评论 0 19
  • 文/苍兰香墨 我抬头看了看天上的太阳。三九已至,却和暖如春,着一层夹袄步出监牢的瞬间,已是汗流浃背。 一阵脚步声响...
    开封第一讲书人阅读 31,197评论 1 260
  • 我被黑心中介骗来泰国打工, 没想到刚下飞机就差点儿被人妖公主榨干…… 1. 我叫王不留,地道东北人。 一个月前我还...
    沈念sama阅读 44,996评论 2 349
  • 正文 我出身青楼,却偏偏与公主长得像,于是被迫代替她去往敌国和亲。 传闻我的和亲对象是个残疾皇子,可洞房花烛夜当晚...
    茶点故事阅读 42,481评论 2 342

推荐阅读更多精彩内容